Reykjavík Grapevine - 19.06.2015, Blaðsíða 10

Reykjavík Grapevine - 19.06.2015, Blaðsíða 10
The Reykjavík Grapevine Politics | Bright? depleting Iceland of all its currency. The Icelandic capital controls are not com- parable to the capital controls in Cyprus, which were put in place to keep money in the Cypriot banks and prevent them from collapsing as funds flowed out due to wild uncertainty. Some 500 billion ISK of the 2,200 billion ISK in the three estates are in ISK, the rest in FX. Now, why have the creditors not been paid out the FX? The answer is that nothing can be paid out of estates to general creditors until the es- tates either go into composition or bank- ruptcy. The winding-up boards of Glitnir and Kaupthing applied for a composi- tion in 2012 and 2013, but little to noth- ing came out of that, as the government was unsure of how to proceed. Because payouts would have followed a compo- sition, the government could not agree to a composition until it was clear what would happen to the ISK paid to credi- tors. An outline of the new plan to lift capital controls First, some media trivia: since the gov- ernment came to power it has been promising a final plan to lift the controls. Every now and then, what they seemed to be working on ended up in the Ice- landic media, always through the same journalist, Hörður Ægisson, with Mor- gunblaðið, until earlier this year when he moved over to DV, as new owners, who are close to the Progressive party hierar- chy, took over that paper. Then the leaks moved to DV, via Hörður. In March, the Ministry of Finance announced that ev- eryone working on the capital controls had to sign a non-disclosure agreement threatening fines, if not fire and brim- stone, to everyone who abused their in- sight. Then, the Friday before the plan was announced, Hörður more or less spilled the plan on the pages of DV. In spite of the measures taken to prevent leaks, nothing has been heard of any ac- tion to clarify the leak. The government has defined the problem keeping the controls in place as amounting to 1,200 billion ISK, ap- proximately 60% of Icelandic GDP, di- vided thusly: the old overhang is 300 billion ISK; the problem in the estates of the three failed bank is 400 billion ISK, i.e. debt that Icelandic entities (mostly because they have FX income) repay in FX; and lastly is 500 billion ISK, which is purely ISK assets, the largest being Glitnir’s holding in Íslandsbanki and Kaupthing’s holding in Arion. It can be argued that the 400 billion ISK is not part of the problem at all since these liabilities, paid in FX anyway, do not need to be converted. But the govern- ment, perhaps rather maximising than minimising the problems looking for resolution, sees these 400 billion ISK as part of the problem. The plan rests on one assumption: in order to limit the outflow of FX, the foreign-owned ISK needs to be reined in before the controls are lifted. The old overhang will be dealt with in autumn: more CBI auction and offer of long-term bonds, all simple and clear. This then leaves the 900 billion ISK (according to the government; others say 500 billion ISK, see above). In order to prevent these sums from wrecking the economy the government has told credi- tors that any solution needs to meet what it calls “stability conditions.” These con- ditions are “non-negotiable,” according to the government plan, but what exactly this means in krónur, i.e. how short the “haircut” needs to be, is not stated. There are now two ways to meet these “stability conditions”: the first option is that the winding-up boards, which run the failed estates, negotiate a composition (which means that the es- tates are in essence run like a company, with assets sold off over time, to maxi- mise return for the creditors, who are then paid out when the funds are in cash; there is already plenty of cash in both estates) before the end of the year and agree to pay voluntarily a so-called “sta- bility contribution” to satisfy the “stabil- ity conditions.” Again, this contribution, paid to the state over two to three years, is not a fixed sum but depends on the value of assets and other variables over the next two or three years. According to Minister of Finance Bjarni Benediktsson this could be as much as 500 billion ISK; calculations I have seen range between 300 billion ISK to 420 billion ISK. The reason for this difference is simply that the there is an optimistic estimate and a less optimistic one as to how the underly- ing variables will develop over the time the contribution is to be paid. If a composition agreement is not reached before the end of the year, the estates go into bankruptcy. This is not the desired course of events from the point of view of creditors, mainly be- cause bankruptcy im- plies a limited time to sell assets, which again will most likely mean lower prices and less recovery. Also—and most importantly—a bankrupt estate will in- cur a tax of 39%, or 850 billion ISK, reduced by certain deductions to 680 ISK (or, more likely, to 620 billion ISK), pay- able by April 15 next year. Here, bankruptcy and the “stability tax” is the stick because this is not what the creditors want, whereas a “stabil- ity contribution” and composition is the carrot the creditors are aiming for. Now, you might ask why the govern- ment agrees to “only” 300 billion ISK to 420 billion ISK or thereabouts if it could possibly get 700 billion ISK or even more. The reason is that there are all sorts of le- gal uncertainties connected to the bank- ruptcy tax: creditors might challenge it in court and even though the govern- ment might win (not necessarily likely, but who knows), this will cause delays, no controls lifted and Iceland stays in limbo. Another gain for Iceland from a successful implementation of the plan: rating agencies, who decide the cost of borrowing for countries and companies, will pay attention. If they are unhappy with how Iceland treats creditors, both the Icelandic state and Icelandic compa- nies get punished with high borrowing costs, not an ideal situation. The sensible people advising the gov- ernment and most of those working on capital controls issues in the CBI and the Ministry of Finance support dangling the “carrot.” With the plan agreed to, this is the likely way. The only thing that could scupper the plan is “panic poli- tics”—politics that arise when politicians are in panic about losing power. The next election is in 2017, and already next year politicians will be planning for it. Over decades, many foreigners have com- plained that the old Roman saying “Pacta sunt servanda” (“an agreement stands”) has never reached Iceland, that Iceland- ers only feel that an agreement stands as long as they do not think of a new one. So there are some caveats as to what could happen—though for the time being, com- position and stability contribution are the likely outcome. So when will those yearning for a flat in the sun or foreign shares or pen- sion funds with billions to invest get out of the controls? Although the rhetoric when the plan was presented was that this was all done with the interests of the “real economy” at heart, i.e. Icelanders, businesses and pension funds, there was no date for lifting the controls for them. That plan will come in autumn or next winter, according to sources close to the government. This will take some years to carry out. How can Iceland allow creditors who will make zillions on their claims to walk away with their huge profits? Well, be- fore profits, there have been huge losses, but not necessarily for the same credi- tors. There are essentially two types of creditors. One type is the foreign banks that originally lent the Icelandic banks and who have lost what amounts to five or six GDPs. The three estates now own assets worth approximately 2200 billion ISK, approximately 110% of Ice- landic GDP. No need to weep over their losses, as some of those original lenders still hold onto their claims, hoping they will get something in the end; they can now hope for around 10% of what they lent Landsbanki, 20% of what they lent to Kaupthing and approximately 30% of what they lent to Glitnir. The second type is those creditors who have bought claims (to begin with from the original lenders, type one; later also from each other) on the so-called “secondary mar- ket,” after the banks had failed. Bank- ruptcy assets are called “distressed assets,” and make up a small but lucra- tive part of the fi- nancial sector. It is a myth that those who bought the claims after the collapse all did so at two cents to the dollar and stand to make thirty or forty. There was very little trade to begin with and the price soon rose but yes, some of those who bought on the secondary market will make a lot and that is the way it goes. It is however important to keep in mind that their profit comes from the estates of failed banks, not from the Icelandic state and Icelandic taxpayers. If Iceland treats the creditors harsh- ly, it may scare away foreign investors, sorely needed at the moment. Although that being said, the finance market tends to forget quickly. Shortly after the last election, in a discussion about capital controls at an open meeting in Reykja- vík, one businessman advocated for the harsh treatment: the estates should just be boxed in and the controls lifted on everyone and everything Icelandic— people, companies and pension funds. Már Guðmundsson, the governor of the CBI, was present and in his calm and measured central banker tone, he said that this was certainly possible. Then, in a few years time, foreign investors will come to Iceland, see the cage, and ask who is in it. “Well, those are the foreign investors who were here last time…” Economy | Capital controls NEWS IN BRIEF the purchase of the newspaper DV, MPs from both the ruling coalition and opposition have called for a closer examination into the matter. The PM has denied any wrongdoing. In other news, Russian sailboat STS Kruzenshtern, which had been docked for several days in the Reykjavík Harbour, accidentally rammed into not one, but two of Iceland’s Coast Guard vessels. Although the Coast Guard is prob- ably furious that the ships have been made unseaworthy, our money is on them also being impressed with an unarmed sailboat doing so much damage to two armoured ships. The Coast Guard also made headlines when they announced that they will return the cache of guns they got from Norway. The 250 MP5 sub- machine guns have been stuck in cus- toms since October, after a disagree- ment about whether the guns were being purchased or if they were gifts. Despite numerous attempts from the Coast Guard and police to convince the general public that they needed such a vast number of firearms, the populace remained firmly opposed to the idea, and now the guns are going home before the end of June. At last, a farewell to arms. And in other good news, arthouse cinema Bíó Paradís successfully crowd-sourced 30,000 EUR to make the venue fully accessible to wheelchair users, hitting their target at the eleventh hour. The plans include installing multiple ramps, building a new toilet, and making numerous other smaller changes throughout the cinema. To end things on a high note, Reykjavík’s petting zoo has seen an increase in its number of in- habitants, with a new foal, baby seal, and for the first time in seven years, a purebred reindeer calf. Although all three can be seen at the petting zoo, the staff has asked visitors to be re- spectful of its denizens, in particular its youngest members. “Over decades, many foreigners have com- plained that the old Roman saying “Pacta sunt servanda” (“an agreement stands”) has never reached Iceland, that Iceland- ers only feel that an agreement stands as long as they do not think of a new one.”
Blaðsíða 1
Blaðsíða 2
Blaðsíða 3
Blaðsíða 4
Blaðsíða 5
Blaðsíða 6
Blaðsíða 7
Blaðsíða 8
Blaðsíða 9
Blaðsíða 10
Blaðsíða 11
Blaðsíða 12
Blaðsíða 13
Blaðsíða 14
Blaðsíða 15
Blaðsíða 16
Blaðsíða 17
Blaðsíða 18
Blaðsíða 19
Blaðsíða 20
Blaðsíða 21
Blaðsíða 22
Blaðsíða 23
Blaðsíða 24
Blaðsíða 25
Blaðsíða 26
Blaðsíða 27
Blaðsíða 28
Blaðsíða 29
Blaðsíða 30
Blaðsíða 31
Blaðsíða 32
Blaðsíða 33
Blaðsíða 34
Blaðsíða 35
Blaðsíða 36
Blaðsíða 37
Blaðsíða 38
Blaðsíða 39
Blaðsíða 40
Blaðsíða 41
Blaðsíða 42
Blaðsíða 43
Blaðsíða 44
Blaðsíða 45
Blaðsíða 46
Blaðsíða 47
Blaðsíða 48
Blaðsíða 49
Blaðsíða 50
Blaðsíða 51
Blaðsíða 52
Blaðsíða 53
Blaðsíða 54
Blaðsíða 55
Blaðsíða 56
Blaðsíða 57
Blaðsíða 58
Blaðsíða 59
Blaðsíða 60
Blaðsíða 61
Blaðsíða 62
Blaðsíða 63
Blaðsíða 64

x

Reykjavík Grapevine

Beinir tenglar

Ef þú vilt tengja á þennan titil, vinsamlegast notaðu þessa tengla:

Tengja á þennan titil: Reykjavík Grapevine
https://timarit.is/publication/943

Tengja á þetta tölublað:

Tengja á þessa síðu:

Tengja á þessa grein:

Vinsamlegast ekki tengja beint á myndir eða PDF skjöl á Tímarit.is þar sem slíkar slóðir geta breyst án fyrirvara. Notið slóðirnar hér fyrir ofan til að tengja á vefinn.