Helga Law Journal - 01.01.2021, Side 77

Helga Law Journal - 01.01.2021, Side 77
Helga Law Journal Vol. 1, 2021 78 Helga Guðmundsdóttir 79 1 Introduction Much like a classic playwright tragedy, the playing out of the ‘tragedy of the commons’ theory has the ultimate outcome that the protagonist’s self-interest results in a catastrophic ending. In particular, the gist of the theory is that unconstrained exploitation of a shared resource by parties acting only in accordance with their own interests can result in the ultimate devastation of that resource.1 The risk that the tragedy of the commons actualizes in respect to the exploitation of fish stocks has likely been increased with the effects of climate change. Scientists estimate that 70 or more countries will experience distribution of new fish stocks within their exclusive economic zones (‘EEZ’) due to changed migration patterns resulting from warming waters by the year 2100 if the current trajectory of greenhouse gas emissions is not halted.2 While climate change mitigation is critical, it is imperative that governments recognize the effects already transpiring and consider how to adapt to the changing patterns of shared fish stocks (that is, stocks that fall under the jurisdiction of two or more States). Where governments are unable to agree on the appropriate management measures, they may become deadlocked in disputes, in particular over each party’s share of a particular fish stock’s overall quota, resulting in all parties overfishing the common stock. An example of such deadlock is the over one decade-long dispute concerning the North East Atlantic mackerel stock (between the European Union (‘EU’), Norway, the Faroe Islands, Iceland and Greenland), which has appeared in the headlines with the EU threatening sanctions against Iceland and Greenland in an attempt to force them to reduce their unilaterally set quotas.3 This dispute is a prime example of parties failing to agree on how much of a shared stock each of them is entitled to fish, resulting in the fisheries of the mackerel far exceeding the quota recommended by scientists to ensure its proper conservation – ultimately threatening the very existence of this stock. To phrase it more dramatically, these parties have set the stage for a rendition of a classic tragedy – the Tragedy of the Commons – the finale of which is unsurprisingly not looking particularly joyful. In this article, I suggest that parties to protracted fisheries disputes – and, in particular, the parties to the mackerel dispute – make use of the tools already available in the law of the sea framework, before resorting to other general tools of coercion and – more importantly – before staging the tragedy of the commons. Specifically, the use of the procedure of compulsory conciliation should be introduced to each coastal State’s radar as a potential tool to resolve current and 1 See, e.g. Brett Frischmann, Alain Marciano and Giovanni Ramello, ‘Retrospectives: Tragedy of the Commons After 50 Years’ (2019) 33 Journal of Economic Perspectives 211. 2 ‘Climate change has fish moving faster than regulations can keep up’ (Science Daily, 14 June 2018) <www.sciencedaily.com/releases/2018/06/180614213727.htm> accessed 23 October 2021. 3 Josh Barrie, ‘EU plans to threaten sanctions on Iceland and Greenland as ‘mackerel war’ looms’ (iNews, 20 August 2019) <inews.co.uk/news/politics/mackerel-fishing-eu-sanctions-iceland- greenland-328516> accessed 23 October 2021. further suggests that by resorting to compulsory conciliation the parties to the North East Atlantic mackerel dispute could bring this measure to the fore and not only resolve their own dispute, but also lead the way for future fisheries dispute resolution.
Side 1
Side 2
Side 3
Side 4
Side 5
Side 6
Side 7
Side 8
Side 9
Side 10
Side 11
Side 12
Side 13
Side 14
Side 15
Side 16
Side 17
Side 18
Side 19
Side 20
Side 21
Side 22
Side 23
Side 24
Side 25
Side 26
Side 27
Side 28
Side 29
Side 30
Side 31
Side 32
Side 33
Side 34
Side 35
Side 36
Side 37
Side 38
Side 39
Side 40
Side 41
Side 42
Side 43
Side 44
Side 45
Side 46
Side 47
Side 48
Side 49
Side 50
Side 51
Side 52
Side 53
Side 54
Side 55
Side 56
Side 57
Side 58
Side 59
Side 60
Side 61
Side 62
Side 63
Side 64
Side 65
Side 66
Side 67
Side 68
Side 69
Side 70
Side 71
Side 72
Side 73
Side 74
Side 75
Side 76
Side 77
Side 78
Side 79
Side 80
Side 81
Side 82
Side 83
Side 84
Side 85
Side 86
Side 87
Side 88
Side 89
Side 90
Side 91
Side 92
Side 93
Side 94
Side 95
Side 96
Side 97
Side 98
Side 99
Side 100
Side 101
Side 102
Side 103
Side 104
Side 105
Side 106
Side 107
Side 108
Side 109
Side 110
Side 111
Side 112
Side 113
Side 114
Side 115
Side 116
Side 117
Side 118
Side 119
Side 120
Side 121
Side 122
Side 123
Side 124
Side 125
Side 126
Side 127
Side 128
Side 129
Side 130
Side 131
Side 132
Side 133
Side 134
Side 135
Side 136
Side 137
Side 138
Side 139
Side 140
Side 141
Side 142
Side 143
Side 144
Side 145
Side 146
Side 147
Side 148
Side 149
Side 150
Side 151
Side 152
Side 153
Side 154
Side 155
Side 156
Side 157
Side 158
Side 159
Side 160
Side 161
Side 162
Side 163
Side 164
Side 165
Side 166
Side 167
Side 168
Side 169
Side 170
Side 171
Side 172
Side 173
Side 174
Side 175
Side 176
Side 177
Side 178
Side 179
Side 180
Side 181
Side 182
Side 183
Side 184
Side 185
Side 186
Side 187
Side 188
Side 189
Side 190
Side 191
Side 192
Side 193
Side 194
Side 195
Side 196
Side 197
Side 198
Side 199
Side 200
Side 201
Side 202
Side 203
Side 204
Side 205
Side 206
Side 207
Side 208
Side 209
Side 210
Side 211
Side 212
Side 213
Side 214
Side 215
Side 216
Side 217
Side 218
Side 219
Side 220
Side 221
Side 222
Side 223
Side 224

x

Helga Law Journal

Direkte link

Hvis du vil linke til denne avis/magasin, skal du bruge disse links:

Link til denne avis/magasin: Helga Law Journal
https://timarit.is/publication/1677

Link til dette eksemplar:

Link til denne side:

Link til denne artikel:

Venligst ikke link direkte til billeder eller PDfs på Timarit.is, da sådanne webadresser kan ændres uden advarsel. Brug venligst de angivne webadresser for at linke til sitet.